Macroeconomic theories: not even wrong
Flawed and inconsistent mainstream macroeconomic theories such as efficient market hypothesis are dangerous to society, says Alexander Lipton
Alexander Lipton is a Connection Science Fellow at MIT and an Adjunct Professor of Mathematics at NYU.
Austria-born physicist and Nobel prizewinner Wolfgang Pauli, who was well known for his dry wit and sharp tongue, once described a theory as "not even wrong" – that is, it was so fundamentally flawed that it could not even be used to make meaningful predictions.
Today, the same could be said about mainstream macroeconomic theories – including the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model (DSGEM), modern portfolio theory (MPT), efficient market hypothesis (EMH) and a few others cut from the same intellectual cloth – that completely miss the point and cannot be used in practice.
These theories are not only pointless; they are dangerous. They adversely affect both academic discourse and the practical actions of regulators and politicians. The latter effect, in particular, is crucial and has enormous implications for society at large.
For instance, central banks use DSGEM to shape monetary policy and design banking regulations, but the model omits the banking sector completely and relies on the unconvincing concept of financial intermediation instead. Furthermore, DSGEM has been used by the European Central Bank to forecast the dynamics of the entire European market, rather than individual countries, thus neglecting their obvious differences.
These theories are not only pointless; they are dangerous. They adversely affect both academic discourse and the practical actions of regulators and politicians
From such a bird's-eye view, the introduction of the euro in 1999 looked like a great idea, while it turned out to be a flawed concept threatening the European project as a whole, partly because politicians and central bankers were lacking adequate tools for analysing stocks and flows across Europe.1
Likewise, the rapid proliferation of robo-advisers, who rely almost exclusively on MPT and its variations, is rather worrisome. It is common knowledge that MPT allocations are unstable and do not work out-of-sample; in fact, a simple equal allocation of funds beats MPT-based allocations hands down.
This list can easily be extended further. There are many explanations of macroeconomic theories' flaws – some epistemological, some technical, and some political – but the main reason is clear. Originators of these theories and their disciples have been enamoured of relatively simple physical theories and tried to extend them to the realm of what is essentially social science, rather than physical science, by assuming that asset returns are governed by simple stochastic processes and modelling them accordingly.
At the same time, precisely because they have been dealing with social systems, some of the natural safeguards that have faithfully served physics and mathematics for centuries have been suppressed. In particular, the power of counter-example has been conveniently ignored.
Let's look at EMH. How could it be taken at face value if sudden, unexplained market plunges, such as those that happened in 1973–74 (or, for that matter, in 1873), October 1987, and, more recently, during the infamous flash crash of May 2010, contradict its main premise unequivocally?
Some of the natural safeguards that have faithfully served physics and mathematics for centuries have been suppressed. In particular, the power of counter-example has been conveniently ignored
How could one seriously talk about efficiency knowing full well about the tulip mania of 1636–37, the South Sea bubble, the sub-prime crisis, the Bitcoin bubble and numerous others? EMH confuses the indisputable fact that it is extremely difficult to beat the market with market efficiency. In fact, they are two completely different concepts. The power of these counter-examples alone would have forced physicists to go back to the drawing board and reconsider their main premises, but economists decided to push forward regardless.2
A well-known former chairman of the Federal Reserve testified in a Congressional hearing that he was "in a state of shocked disbelief" because markets turned out to be inefficient. As a result of these misguided views, a number of sensible regulations were abolished, the Glass-Steagall Act was repealed, and the global financial crisis of 2008–09 unfolded. New regulations were introduced after the crisis, including the Dodd-Frank Act. But additional regulations are still required – potentially the reinstatement of the Glass-Steagall Act, or at least an explanation of why it should not be reinstated.
The time has come for quants to look into some of the more ambiguous aspects of macroeconomics and try to build better theories explaining market dynamics and their salient features, propose better asset allocation methods, and generally add much-needed rigour to the discourse. This will help not only their employers and themselves, but also society at large.
1. See, for example, J. Stiglitz, The euro: and its threat to the future of Europe, 2016. I have been opposed to the euro from day one, advocating instead the digitization of national currencies, thus removing frictions – and fighting financial crime along the way – while preserving necessary safety valves. Recent developments in blockchain-related technologies might help to make sovereign-issued digital currencies a reality.
2. By now, true believers in EMH have to rely on the "credo quia absurdum" line of defence first devised by Tertullian in the third century AD.
Only users who have a paid subscription or are part of a corporate subscription are able to print or copy content.
To access these options, along with all other subscription benefits, please contact info@risk.net or view our subscription options here: http://subscriptions.risk.net/subscribe
You are currently unable to print this content. Please contact info@risk.net to find out more.
You are currently unable to copy this content. Please contact info@risk.net to find out more.
Copyright Infopro Digital Limited. All rights reserved.
As outlined in our terms and conditions, https://www.infopro-digital.com/terms-and-conditions/subscriptions/ (point 2.4), printing is limited to a single copy.
If you would like to purchase additional rights please email info@risk.net
Copyright Infopro Digital Limited. All rights reserved.
You may share this content using our article tools. As outlined in our terms and conditions, https://www.infopro-digital.com/terms-and-conditions/subscriptions/ (clause 2.4), an Authorised User may only make one copy of the materials for their own personal use. You must also comply with the restrictions in clause 2.5.
If you would like to purchase additional rights please email info@risk.net
More on Views
Quants dive into FX fixing windows debate
Longer fixing windows may benefit clients, but predicting how dealers will respond is tough
Podcast: Piterbarg and Nowaczyk on running better backtests
Quants discuss new way to extract independent samples from correlated datasets
BofA quants propose new model for when to hold, when to sell
Closed-form formula helps market-makers optimise exit strategies
Podcast: Alvaro Cartea on collusion within trading algos
Oxford-Man Institute director worries ML-based trading could have anti-competitive effects
Podcast: Lorenzo Ravagli on why the skew is for the many
JP Morgan quant proposes a unified framework for trading the volatility skew premium
Counterparty risk model links defaults to portfolio values
Fed’s Michael Pykhtin proposes using copula models to capture effects of margin calls on default risk
Podcast: Olivier Daviaud on P&L attribution for options
JP Morgan quant discusses his alternative to Greeks decomposition
Filling gaps in market data with optimal transport
Julius Baer quant proposes novel way to generate accurate prices for illiquid maturities